The
question of where profits come from has a double signification. The first
argues whether profits are expropriated from the value added by labour, or
whether they are added on, over and above production costs. The second
overrides both possibilities as it wonders where the money to pay for profits
is coming from. Whether profits are unpaid labour or are added to the cost
price, they can only be sold on the market if there is a solvent demand. Money
goes on to the market to invest in goods, services and labour, but the price
paid then comes back on the market increased by a certain amount of profit.
More money comes out of the market than is put in. And this applies whenever
something is sold for more than it has been paid.
The
possibility of more for less originated with monetary transactions, money being
the generally accepted standard measure of exchange value (1). This means that
commodity C is exchanged for money M, and M is exchanged for another commodity
C’. Money changes hands as the intermediary in a chain of exchanged commodities:
C-M-C’-M-C”-M-C”’ etc. So C is sold to buy C’, which is sold to buy C”, which
is sold to buy C”’ etc. This chain can have money as the intermediary between two
commodities, C-M-C’, but it can also have a commodity as the intermediary
between two sums of money, M-C-M’. In the first case the two commodities are
different, which justifies the two exchanges, C-M and M-C’. In the second case
money becomes money again, and the only justification of this double
transaction is that the second exchange, C-M’, involves more money than the
first one, M-C, that M’ is larger than M. Buying to sell, instead of selling to
buy, presupposes a profit. It means getting more value of the same thing, money,
instead of the same value of something different, commodities.
Merchants
were the first to disrupt the exchange of equal values (2). Then some of them
became bankers and demanded interest on credit, and industrialists obtained
more labour than they paid for. All these groups get more money out of the
market than they put in, a supplement that must come from somewhere. In the
past, money was sifted from river beds and dug out of the ground, as gold,
silver, copper and tin. But that made it a commodity that obeyed the rules of
commodity exchange. These metals were exchanges for money before becoming money.
If they were minted, they would increase the number of coins in circulation,
but each one had been paid for. More coins would increase the number of exchanges
that occurred in a given time, but they could not pay the surcharge of profits
and interest as they had previously been paid for. In fact, the only money
created out of thin air is credit, as even bank notes have a cost and their
production is closely controlled. This fiction, which is based on the promise
of a future payment with real money, means that more money can come out of the
market than is put in. However, if profits continue to be reaped, credit must
grow proportionally. It must be renewed and increased. And, as it pays
interest, that must also be compensated by additional credit. So credit swells
and swells some more, until debtors start defaulting and bonds become junk. And
zero interest rates only facilitate credit on an even larger scale.
Some
commodities go into the production process and transmit their values to the end
product. They are invested. Others are consumed and their value is annihilated.
They must be created anew. An invested credit returns its value, and its
renewal will renew the investment. A consumed credit has lost its value, so its
renewal will not renew the consumption, it will just prolong the credit. This
means that credit can cover the profits on investments, and grow at the same
rate as investments. But when credit tries to cover the profits on consumption,
it multiplies much faster than consumption and gets out of hand. (3)
Profits
need to be realised and become money so that they can be invested and accumulate
as capital. This problem, especially for profits on consumption, can be solved
by foreign trade. If finished products for consumption are exported and raw
materials for investments are imported, the transformation occurs elsewhere and
has no effect on the home market. This exchange was the original motive for
trading abroad and the basis of colonialism. The colonialists would receive
consumption from the metropolis, and send back raw or rare materials produced
by native labour. Neo-colonialism maintained the system by furnishing local
potentates with luxury goods, palaces and weapons in exchange for their
country’s natural resources. And the only investments have been ports, railways,
pipelines and roads to transport those resources. However, the planet is finite
and there is competition among industrial nations to control this advantageous
trade. The colonial powers of the past finally fought it out and were ruined.
Today’s imperial powers are restrained by mass mutual destruction, but their
necessary expansion is a path to confrontation. The new giant with a billion
workers and the arch-bully with most of the world’s weaponry may be edging
towards such a clash, which could lead to a new division of the planet and a
Second Cold War.
Profits
can become investments by resorting to credit and lop-sided global trade. But
neither solution is perennial, as the first ends in collapsed credit bubbles,
and the second in world wars. However investments are a necessary part of
production – the renewal and upkeep of existing ones and the production of new
and innovative ones – and the wherewithal to pay for them must come from
somewhere. The present problem is, and this was probably true a century ago,
that the sum of profits is far larger than the sum of productive investments
that are made. For example, Apple has $200B in off-shore profits and is
bringing some of them to the US at minimal cost, not to invest in production or
R&D, not to build schools in Jackson, Montgomery and Atlanta, just to buy
back a large wad of its own shares and push up the price of those still on the
market. The disconnection between the sums trying to make a profit and the sums
used to produce more goods and services has transformed the world’s stock
exchanges into vast Ponzi structures that keep going as long as new money is
being added to the pot. When that stops, everyone discovers that the pot only
contains worthless bits of paper. It is imaginable that investments could be
restricted to increasing and improving production and productivity. The other
existing forms might not be outlawed, but might be frowned on as perverse and
sick-brained, like usury and gambling. But the world cannot be remade, its
finality is profit, and the existing rules of fear, contempt, envy, hate and
hubris will wreak their usual havoc and destruction.
1.
It seems that the use of credit for exchanges preceded the use of coins by a
couple of thousand years. See David Graeber’s book, Debt: The first 5000 years.
2.
Landowners have obtained rent from time immemorial. But rent, like taxes, is
just money changing hands, the weak to the strong, those who have not to those
who have.