In the wake of other industrial nations the
growth of China’s productive capacity has been so fast and on such a gigantic
scale that it can be seen as a perfect example of capitalist accumulation. A
process pioneered by England at the dawn of mechanised mass production. A path
followed by all of today’s richest nations. In 1949, after a century of
colonial plundering (1st Opium War 1840-1842), a Japanese invasion
and a protracted civil war, China was in a wretched state. Sixty-six years
later it has become the world’s second largest economy, and is probably the
first for manufactured goods. How has so much wealth been produced and
accumulated in a lifetime?
Industrialisation begins with coal and
steel, and needs protection from foreign competition. Most nations have managed
this with prohibitive tariff barriers. China was a communist pariah behind a
“bamboo curtain” and, before the split in 1960, the USSR was providing
technical assistance, but it was using all its own coal and steel for
reconstruction at home. This first stage consists in building steel works to
build more steel works and the transport infrastructure between them and their
sources of coal and ore. Meanwhile, consumption is either at a standstill or in
regression, as its production is neglected and its labour force is diverted to
mining, to building canals, railroads, etc. However, productive capacity,
energy supplies and transport do not increase indefinitely without ultimate
consumption. This will be military consumption and, in the case of war, the
early frugality will get worse. In peace or cold war, civilian consumption of
coal and steel will relay the military.
The first stage of industrial development
can occur behind closed borders because coal and iron are found just about
everywhere. But subsequent expansion needs raw materials and technology that
must be traded for. But, after the ideological break with Moscow, China’s only
remaining allies were Albania and North Korea. The 1960s were a time of
political turmoil, but then Nixon decided to get out of Vietnam and visited
Peking. 1972 was the turning point when Mao handed over to Zhou – who would
bring back Deng, who in turn would facilitate Jiang, Hu and Xi – and when
foreign trade became possible. A ruling class intent on the accumulation of
capital needs to import investments not consumption, and to balance its trade
it needs to export consumption not investments. The ideal case is the
importation of raw materials, their transformation and their exportation. (This
is what the English did with cotton in the early 19th century, and
tariff barriers on cheap imported cereals were only lifted in 1846. Cheap bred
that may have helped to prevent the upheavals that spread across Europe in 1848
from crossing the Channel.) China did not have much consumption to offer, and
the little they did produce was of inferior quality, though it was very
inexpensive. Price was the deciding factor, and shoddy clothes and tools were
soon to be found everywhere. Made in China was a pejorative term, just as Made
in Japan had been twenty years earlier. Since the 1960s, Japan had managed to
develop its own domains of excellence, with motorcars and bikes, cameras and
electronics. In the 1980s China faced a far more competitive situation, with
three industrial poles, North America, Western Europe, Japan and the Asian
Tigers, dominating the world. It was also the time when large corporations were
going global and were beginning to make things outside their national base.
Instead of exporting finished products, they built factories abroad for a final
assemblage to supply the local demand. An early example was a VW factory in
Brazil in 1957. This use of cheap labour abroad brought down costs and made
their products more affordable. Inevitably, some companies soon realised that
these cost reductions would be even more profitable on their home market. It
was the beginning of outsourced production and the multiplication of maritime
and air freight. When China opened up to foreign investments in joint-ventures,
some businesses were attracted by the idea of a vast number of potential new
customers, while others were more interested by the huge potential of a
disciplined capable work force for next to nothing. Predictably, the Chinese
did not have the means to increase their consumption – that would come later –
so practically all the new production was shipped out to the world, along with
large quantities of counterfeit goods.
Importing investments and exporting
consumption is the perfect mechanism for accumulating capital. However, it
produces such a strain, nationally and internationally, that it is always
short-lived. Global capitalism expands and rakes in profits, but nations
suffer. At home production is increasing, but the labour force is not any
better off, and sometimes the move from agriculture to industry has worsened
their living conditions. Abroad the trade advantage becomes a disadvantage, as
other nations are necessarily importing consumption and exporting investments.
They are not increasing their investments, and may even be reducing them in
some sectors. In these nations the supply of consumption increases but labour’s
incomes are stagnant or in regression as “services” replace industrial jobs.
This is resolved by easy credit and the accumulation of debts. There is also a
rising trade deficit because their exported investments come back with added
value.
The first nations to transform consumption into investments in foreign
countries did it by colonial conquest and exploitation, guns and ammunition to
take gold, slaves and land. The exception was Germany. Founded in 1870 the
German nation had missed out on the world’s division during the previous three
centuries, and was just in time to participate in the final carving up of
Africa in the 1890s. Deprived of colonial bounty, Germans privileged technology
and became leaders in industrial chemistry and mechanics. They also export
consumption, but more importantly they export intermediary goods such as dyes
and machines. These products are sold to industrial nations and the proceeds
pay for Germany’s raw materials. This exchanges investments for investments,
but the outgoing trade contains far more added value than the incoming one and
allows the accumulation of capital. Japan was also a latecomer to colonial
plunder, Korea 1910, Manchuria 1931, China 1937, and briefly down as far as the
Philippines. In the 1950s the Japanese started exporting consumer goods and,
having specialized, they took market shares in the other industrial nations,
while protecting themselves from consumer imports (notably food) with tariff
barriers.
China’s path to industrial development had similarities with the Japanese
way and considerable differences. The main difference was that Chinese industry
was state owned and, due to China’s isolation, was decades behind the times.
There were no Chinese equivalents of Mitsubishi, Honda, Canon, Sony, etc. who
could research and develop themselves to world stature and impose their brand.
Another difference was that the Chinese market did not need much protection as
there was no affluent middle class with the means to buy imported consumption.
Anyway the state had total control. The resemblance with Japan was to trade
consumption for investments with industrial nations. The first problem was
resolved when joint-ventures had top brands from everywhere flocking to China’s
shores. The second difference lasted for a while and the outflow of consumption
grew as fast as the inflow of investments. The accumulation of capital was as
effective as ever, and its speed and dimensions were those of the age. Hence,
in a record time, the usual stresses cause by this gigantic pump of investments
started to provoke reactions. At home, a blooming middle class of small
entrepreneurs, retailers, restaurateurs, and members of the medical, legal and
teaching professions were increasing their incomes and encouraging the working
class from whence they came to do the same. Abroad, the outflow of investments
and the inflow of consumption were destroying jobs and creating debts. This was
when some began to say that Chinese goods should be consumed in China instead
of being exported, and that factories would come back to their nations of
origin. So the Chinese middle class took on debts like their counterparts elsewhere,
which gave capital another lease of growth, but there was little or no return
of manufacturing to America, Japan and Western Europe, as pay and working
hours, not to mention environmental and security regulations, are incomparable.
Just like its predecessors, China has accumulated capital by trading its
consumption for the world’s investments. When that process slowed down, China
turned to creating demand at home by granting credit. Capital has always had
recourse to consumer credit to monetize its surplus value and turn consumption
into investments. But in the past it was only granted to governments and to the
wealthier members of society, other people visited the pawnbroker. Then, at the
beginning of the last century, businessmen like Henry Ford realised that the
working class did not need collateral to be credit worthy. Since then credit
has spread to all consumption, public and private. And it is now apparent that
industrial nations have spent several years of their future incomes, and that
the interest on this combined debt is greater than the growth rate of incomes. As
for paying it back, that would dry up consumption completely, as well as
profits and all the rest.
China’s accumulation of capital was fuelled by foreign trade, and the
nations they were trading with were having to borrow to pay for added value
they had not produced (those few cents on a smart phone). This came on top of
labour’s borrowing to cover its own unpaid added value. Together they formed a
debt balloon that deflated in 2007 and brought China’s trade growth to a halt.
However, its production was growing at such a rate that it could not be
suddenly curbed, so Chinese consumers both big and small were given a wide
access to credit. It would seem that spending one’s future incomes is an
acquired habit, and many unhabituated Chinese have used this easy money to
invest on the stock market instead of buying cars and washing machines. They
even thought for a while that their investments would be profitable, but market
speculation is about as subprime as a debt can get, so that China is in turn on
the verge of a debt default crisis. It is showing the world that it is a
fully-fledged member of the capitalist club, all of them up to their necks in
paper promises.