Multinational profiteering
Marx
reasoned that the value supplied to the market equalled c+v+s, where
c was the used up means of production, or constant capital: inputs of
raw or unfinished materials and energy, and the ware and redundancy
of machines and buildings; v was the wages of labour, or variable
capital: take home incomes and taxes, insurances et cetera; and s was
the tribute to property, or surplus value: rents, interest, corporate
and commercial profits, and more taxes, insurances et cetera. Having
considered a third department for luxury consumption, Marx finally
simplified his model to department I producing the means of
production and department II producing the means of consumption.
Department
I 4000c + 1000v + 1000s = 6000 (means of production)
Department
II 2000c + 500v + 500s = 3000 (means of consumption)
This
model of simple reproduction without growth shows how the added value
(1500v + 1500s) equals the value to be consumed, and the used up
investments (4000c + 2000c) equal the new ones produced. It reflects
19th century capitalism. Since then the proportion of
means of production to means of consumption in developed economies
has been inverted and more, with as much 75% of the value realised
going to consumption.
For
capital to accumulate, surplus value must be invested instead of
being consumed, so some means of consumption must somehow be
transformed into means of production. How can the end produce of
department II increase the end produce of department I? Some can go
to increasing the amount of labour (v), if it is appropriate, but an
increase in department I’s means of production (c) must come either
from those of department II, or from outside the system. The first
case is a closed circuit that requires a very centralised
authoritarian government, because reducing the means of production
destined to department II results in less means of consumption for
everyone. And continually favouring department I pauperises
department II. The second case depends on imperialist laissez faire
to exchange means of consumption for means of production on external
markets. It is basically a belligerent process (markets are
conquered), but it allows both departments to develop simultaneously.
The crudest form of this exchange is guns for minerals, but it exists
in numerous other guises where more or less finished products are
exchanged for ones that are less so. More added value is exported
than is imported, and the corresponding consumption takes place
elsewhere. This kind of accumulation can only be practised by a few
nations at a time and is detrimental to their trading partners, who
exchange means of production for means of consumption, who consume
their capital instead of capitalising their consumption. The
unilateral exchange of added value is the principal method for
accumulating capital and has enriched all the developed nations. It
is now benefiting the developing nations, who have reversed the flow
of added value in their favour by importing factories, as well as raw
materials, and exporting their produce.
Outsourcing
parts of department II was a quest for low-paid disciplined labour,
but it brought about a new phase in capitalist expansion. The
industrial nations had developed by exporting consumer goods and
importing raw materials. Both departments operated inside imperial
boundaries, protected by tariffs and armies. With spreading
independence from colonial rule, those sectors of department I
involved in producing raw materials were the first to be expatriated.
This did not modify the flow of added value, but it inaugurated the
multinational corporation. Then the fall of the USSR, the end of the
Cold War and China joining the OMC gave an opening for capitalist
expansion into an immense new domain. As it had been in the past,
China was the focus of attention. Its myriads of potential customers
would revive demand on stagnant clogged-up Western markets. China had
developed the fundamentals of industrialisation that are education,
coal and steel, cement, energy, communications and military, with the
aid of the USSR and then on its own after their split in 1960. And,
having followed the same path as its neighbour (the first case given
above), China was equally unable to develop its department II. The
basic means of production were there, but the passage to means of
consumption needed private initiatives and the stimulus of social
success. It also needed advanced technology to catch up with the
world. The Chinese knew of course that it is better to receive
fishing-tackle than fish, and better still to make the tackle. They
opened up to joint ventures, supplying energy, buildings and
infrastructures to receive the foreign production processes and a
literate, disciplined low-cost labour force. What may have been
conceived as an entry to the Chinese consumer market, turned out to
be an outsourcing of consumer production for the home market.
The
models of exchanges between departments I and II used by Marx are
closed systems. His description of capitalism was to go from the
general to the particular, but politics, illness and death prevented
its completion. Also he lived in a time of empires, when trade
between imperial nations was quite restricted. However, these
exchanges were partly international even then, and became
increasingly so after WW2 with the numerous national liberations from
colonialism, and again since the end of the Cold War. As the colonies
had largely served as sources of raw materials for European
industries, parts of department I were outsourced by international
events. This turned out to be as advantageous as and less costly than
colonial dominion. Consumption was transformed into investments as
before, and locals replaced colonials as consumers. Outsourcing
department II was different. It meant transforming investments into
consumption without producing the final added value, so that more
came back than went out. This was not apparent at first as the demand
for investments revived department I and the outflow of value
dominated the return. But then the tide turned and demand for
department I passed from capital investment to capital renewal with
local know-how, and the value of previous investments came back with
value added by outside labour. The multinational corporations who had
often seen this happen before, when consumer goods flooded markets
and destroyed local productions in the undeveloped world, advised
(ordered?) the same solution for the developed nations: let them eat
debt!
1.
An investment that goes into the production process either transmits
its value or acquires more value. Consumption is consumed and its
value must be produced again. Dividing them into two distinct
departments is unrealistic because of all the overlaps, where the
same products (e.g. cars) can be either investments or consumption.
However, Marx’s model gives a general idea. There are also
investments involving no transformations and little or no added
value, which are buying to sell for a profit and lending at interest.