Rosa Luxemburg
Ever
since it was published in 1913, Rosa Luxemburg’s The
Accumulation of Capital has often been criticised (1). Among the
first was Otto Bauer, who prompted Luxemburg to publish an
Anti-Critique in 1915 (2). The debate was, and still is, about the
future of capitalism. Can it exist of itself, or does it need to
continually expand and conquer?
To
illustrate his reasoning, Marx had constructed several mathematical
models, for simple reproduction and then for expanded reproduction.
They would become the centre of the controversy. Luxemburg had dealt
with them quite quickly to concentrate on the material forces rather
than arbitrary numbers. But her adversaries harped back to the
models, and even built new and more complex ones.
For
his model, Marx had imagined a world wholly divided between capital
and labour, between the owners of capital and salaried workers of all
kinds. Then he split production into investments and consumption, the
produce that goes back into the production process (I) and the
produce that does not (II). Finally he separated the composition of
the value produced into constant capital (c), comprising the wear and
tear of buildings and machines, and inputs such as energy and raw
materials or unfinished products; variable capital (v), which is the
cost of labour, the value of its renewal; and surplus value (s) being
the unpaid value added by the work force.
I:
c1 + v1 + s1 = value of investments produced
II:
c2 + v2 + s2 = value of consumption produced
Marx
used his model to explain pre-capitalist simple reproduction, where
c1 + c2 = investments and v1 + s1 + v2 + s2 = consumption. A somewhat
fictitious situation, as production has grown and regressed
throughout history, though growth did take on a different dimension
after the industrial revolution. The used up investments are renewed,
and wages and surplus value are consumed. The c2 part of consumption
is exchanged for the v1 + s1 part of investments.
Marx
then used his model to explain expanded reproduction, where a part of
surplus value is used to increase constant and variable capital. For
this he chose two sets of numbers, the first with a 10% growth in
both departments, the second with half the surplus value of each
department being invested.
I.
4400c+1100v+1100s=6600
II. 1600c+800v+800s=3200
Total =9800
II. 1600c+800v+800s=3200
Total =9800
I.
4840c+1210v+1210s=7260
II. 1760c+880v+880s=3520
Total =10780
II. 1760c+880v+880s=3520
Total =10780
I.
5324c+1331v+1331s=7986
II. 1936c+968v+968s=3872
Total =11858
II. 1936c+968v+968s=3872
Total =11858
I.
5856c+1464v+1464s=8784
II. 2129c+1065v+1065s=4259
Total =13043
II. 2129c+1065v+1065s=4259
Total =13043
(3)
And
the second case:
I.
5000c + 1000v + 1000s = 7000
II.
1430c + 285v + 285s = 2000
Total
= 9000
I.
5417c + 1083v + 1083s = 7583
II.
1583c + 316v + 316s = 2215
Total
= 9798
I.
5869c + 1173v + 1173s = 8215
II.
1715c + 342v + 342s = 2399
Total
= 10614
I.
6358c + 1271v + 1271s = 8900
II.
1858c + 371v + 371s = 2600
Total
= 11500
(4)
Both
sets of numbers work and give an infinite series of accumulated
capital. But Marx was not happy with the results, and Luxemburg would
highlight his dissatisfaction. “How
can they continually draw 600 p.st. out of circulation, when they
continually, throw only 500 p.st. into it? From nothing comes
nothing. The capitalist class as a whole cannot draw out of
circulation what was not previously in it.”
And
“Here
the same question reappears, which we met previously. Where does the
additional money come from, by which the additional surplus value now
contained in the form of commodities is to be realised?”
(5). In fact the problem goes back to the beginning of Marx’s
quest, when he was pondering on exchange: commodity-money-commodity
and money-commodity-money. In the first case, money is the
intermediary for the exchange of different commodities that have the
same value. In the second case, a commodity is the intermediary for
the exchange of the same money but of different values. Buying to
sell means getting more value out of the double exchange than was put
in. If everyone is buying to sell at a higher price, “where does
the additional money come from?” The same goes for buying labour
and selling its unpaid added value.
Luxemburg
proclaimed that Marx’s models could prove nothing and that, in the
real world, capitalism expanded by plundering the planet. And even
when neocolonialism replaced imperialism, the trade of guns and other
ordnance, as well as food and luxury goods, for oil, uranium, copper,
coltan, etc., continued to transform consumption into investments. In
fact this trade between developed and “developing” nations had
already begun in Luxemburg’s time. Her chapter on international
loans describes how they all come back to their source as payments
for various industrial goods. British, German and French banks were
financing the construction of railways with European steel by
granting credit to Argentina, the USA, Turkey and Russia, while Egypt
wasted vast sums on wild and unsuccessful projects (6). Credit was
where the money was coming from. Instead of bartering with the
natives, capital was granting them credit to realise its surplus
value and get interest as well.
Luxemburg
hardly mentioned credit, once to approve Bulgakov, “it is the
development of the institution of credit which accompanies the
development of capitalist economy. (Hear, hear!) Credit has the
tendency to diminish the amount of money in circulation (this
decrease being, of course, only relative, not absolute); it is the
necessary complement of a developing economy of exchange which would
otherwise soon find itself hampered by a lack of coined money.”
(7) and in a quote from Capital III, “Let us furthermore make
exceptions of fluctuations of prices which prevent large portions of
the total capital from reproducing themselves under average
conditions and which, owing to the general interrelations of the
entire process of reproduction, such as are developed particularly by
credit, must always call forth general stoppages of a transient
nature. Let us also make abstraction of the bogus transactions and
speculations, which the credit system favours.” (8) But then
she lived in a world where gold and silver coins were still legal
tender, and where consumer credit, except for the very rich, was
limited to the pawnbroker or to an agreement between storekeeper and
customer. It was long before plastic cards and subprime lending.
Nowadays, the preponderance of credit makes its function, as an
unlimited substitute for money, seem quite obvious. Surplus value is
paid for with credit granted abroad and at home. However, invested
credit is returned with a profit, whereas credit for consumption is
consumed.
Luxemburg
realised that the surplus demand that pays for surplus value had to
come from elsewhere. Colonial plunder and unethical trade explain
some of that demand, but most of it comes out of thin air as promises
of future payments, as credit. David Graeber has shown convincingly
that credit predated money by a few thousand years (9). The legendary
Phrygian king Midas is said to have minted the first coins to pay his
(mercenary?) army. The Greeks took up the idea and built a commercial
empire. Bullion and coins became the means of payment, the
representation of value and value in itself. This did not stop credit
being granted in many transactions, but gold and silver were the
standards against which all values were measured. Unfortunately, the
supply of precious metals was subjected to considerable historic
fluctuations, along with the subsequent disorders. The gold standard
was finally abandoned in 1971 (see the “Nixon shock”) and, after
some confusion, money and credit could finally assume their roles as
virtual scriptural entities, one measuring past payments and the
other measuring future payments. And the value of this measure is
based on a “basket” of goods and services.
Since
its distant origins, money and credit had been constrained by the
supply of gold. The Nixon administration’s decision set them free
to expand at will, and credit could pay for more and more surplus
value. However, invested credit and consumed credit are not the same.
The first comes back and can be renewed. The second does not.
Invested credit grows at the same rate as investments. Consumed
credit grows at a much faster rate than consumption. Consumer credit
increases consumption, but paying back the credit reduces consumption
because the value has been consumed. This means that to stop the
reduction a new credit must be granted, to maintain the previous
increase a supplementary credit is needed, and to continue the growth
a third one is necessary. “The IMF issued a warning that China’s
“credit efficiency” had deteriorated sharply over the past
decade, with ever larger amounts of money needed to generate the same
amount of growth. “In 2008, new credit of about Rmb6.5tn (approx $1
trillion) was needed to raise nominal GDP by Rmb5tn,” the fund
said. “In 2016 it took Rmb20tn in new credit.” (10) The
amount of credit needed for sustained growth in consumer demand can
quickly get out of control. However, without growth there is no
accumulation and without accumulation capitalism fails.
Postscript
Another
fault of Marx’s model, and of his “epigones”, is that he has
department I producing more than twice the value produced by
department II in the first case, and more than three times in the
second case. Tony Cliff noted this disparity, and gave a set of
figures showing that department I was catching up with department II,
and had overtaken it in the US (1920).
“Thus
it was calculated that the ratio of net output of capital goods to
that of consumer goods was in Britain as follows:
1851,
100:470; 1871, 100:390; 1901, 100:170; 1924, 100:150.
The
figures for the United States were:
1850,
100:240; 1890, 100:150; 1920, 100:80.
The
figures for Japan:
1900,
100:480; 1913, 100:270; 1925, 100:240.”
(11)
This
only shows that department I was investing more and growing faster
than department II, not that it was producing more. Consumption is
actually at 70% of GDP in the US (100/233), and at about 54% for the
world as a whole (100/117). There is no doubt that Marx was just
juggling numbers for his own use, as Capital II and III were his
notes, not the finished form.
Five
years after Rosa Luxemburg was murdered by Noske’s Freikorps thugs
during the Berlin insurrection, Bukharin published a critical
analysis of her work (12). Bukharin was a supporter of Lenin’s New
Economic Policy and wanted to show that capitalism could function.
One can only imagine what Luxemburg’s reaction would have been. She
did have the time to write: “Old
mole. History, you have done your work well! At this moment the
slogan, the warning cry, such as can be raised only in the great
period of global change, again resounds through the International and
the German proletariat. That slogan is: Imperialism or Socialism! War
or Revolution! There is no third way!”
(13)
As well as: “Friedrich
Engels once said: “Bourgeois society stands at the crossroads,
either transition to socialism or regression into barbarism.” What
does “regression into barbarism” mean to our lofty European
civilization? Until now, we have all probably read and repeated these
words thoughtlessly, without suspecting their fearsome seriousness. A
look around us at this moment shows what the regression of bourgeois
society into barbarism means. This world war is a regression into
barbarism. The triumph of imperialism leads to the annihilation of
civilization. At first, this happens sporadically for the duration of
a modern war, but then when the period of unlimited wars begins it
progresses toward its inevitable consequences.”
(14)
1.
Marxists internet archives:
https://www.marxists.org/archive/luxemburg/1913/accumulation-capital/index.htm
The
page numbers are from the Routledge 2003 edition.
2.
https://www.marxists.org/archive/luxemburg/1915/anti-critique/index.htm
Pages
89 & 90
Pages
96 & 97
Pages
133 & 136
Page
281
Page
312
0 Comments:
Post a Comment
<< Home