When might is right
Capital
opposes labour just as investments oppose consumption. Capital wishes
to accumulate investments as fast as possible. And labour aspires to
more leisure and consumption. They compete for a share of the wealth
produced, and the competition can become abusive when one side has
the upper hand. The accumulation of capital may occur at such speed
that it forces labour into poverty and debt. And, mostly in
pre-industrial societies, consumption may leave no part for the
accumulation of capital. Then there are the investments and
consumption of making war, which are detrimental to investments and
consumption for civilian usage. The military get their ordnance and
the people make do with junk food. In this case, accumulation is paid
with taxes and public debts.
Capital
accumulates as the private property of the means of production
(including land), or as the private ownership of loans. These
separate forms of investments are complementary, because the unpaid
added value of production finds a solvent demand thanks to borrowing
(1). The profits of production are paid with debts, and so is
interest. Profit allows the accumulation of productive investments,
and interest does the same for financial investments. This means that
an increasing part of borrowing goes to paying interest, and that
debts grow faster than demand, faster than GDP. At some point,
because of its size, the percentage increase in borrowing can no
longer be maintained, so consumer demand stalls, debt defaults
increase their frequency and the structure starts to fall apart.
To
accumulate as capital, profit and interest must impose an ever
increasing debt load on society. And when it gets unbearably heavy,
there are few available solutions. Basically, they are cancelation,
inflation or reimbursement. Debts can be cancelled in an
authoritarian manner. This was an occasional practice in ancient
Babylonia and a septennial one in Judea, and Solon decreed it in 6th
century BCE Athens, but then the ramifications of debt ownership
became so complicated that this was no longer a realistic option.
Inflation reduces the value of past debts, but it must be in double
digits to be effective, as it was in the 1970s, and that severely
disturbs commercial exchanges because of constantly changing prices.
Debts can be paid back, but that supposes a serious reduction in
spending with a slump in production and employment, and a fall in
profits, interest and accumulation. There is no convenient resolution
for debts.
The
division of production into capital and labour divides society into
employers and employees, amasses debts and leads to disruptive chaos.
This division is artificial. It is the consequence of property rights
that were instituted by violent conquest, when land became private
property and labour was put in bondage. Prior to that, a territory
(the means of production) was commonly owned by those who lived in
it. For thousands of years, armies have plundered foreign lands and
subjected the natives, but this is the result of superior force, it
is not a fatality. After all, labour is future capital and capital is
past labour. Their distinctiveness comes from their ownership, not
from their inherent qualities. And if capital and labour are one and
the same, then investments and consumption are also united as two
parts of a whole. Investments sustain and increase the means of
production, and consumption does the same for the work force. Their
oppositions are not functional, because production, exchange and
consumption are inseparable, they are due to the rights property
gives to rent, interest and profit. And these in turn bring the
disruption of debt accumulation. It is the private ownership of
capital that is driving the world to financial collapse and
destruction. But it would be foolish to pretend that changing it at
short notice is possible. When the rubble settles and the dust
clears, however, a future generation may give it some thought.
1.
For more on the relationship between debt and profit see:
0 Comments:
Post a Comment
<< Home