The unbalance of debt and demand
The
story begins with exchanges for money. Produce (or labour) is sold
for money, which is used to buy something else. Money transfers the
value of the first transaction to the second, and makes them equal.
Different things of same value have been exchanged. In principle that
is, because market forces of supply and demand are constantly
modifying that equality. However, the exchange of commodity (or
labour) for money and of money for commodity (or labour), C’ – M
– C”, once in place, can take the alternative form of money for
commodity and commodity for money, M’ – C – M”. Instead of
money being the intermediary for the exchange of different
commodities of equal value, a commodity is the intermediary for the
exchange of the same money (metal, paper, digital) of different
value. This led to merchants selling goods for more than they had
paid them, to bankers selling money for more than it was worth, and
to manufacturers selling the product of labour for more than they had
paid it. And all this extra value had to come from somewhere.
Monetary
creations can cover the extra value of commercial, financial and
industrial exchanges. Spain did this in the 16th century,
at the dawn of the modern era, with its convoys of American silver.
But the quantities of bullion were soon insufficient, so trade and
credit took the relay. The driving force of Robber Capitalism is
accumulation. In its primary form, capital was land and bonded
labour. As trade developed, gold and silver money, the universal
exchange values, became capital in its ubiquitous perfection.
Finally, with the machine age and the exploitation of fossil fuels,
capital encompassed the means of production. Capital could accumulate
not only as land and money, but also as productive investments. And
these could be procured by trade and credit.
A
part of production concerns investments, and the other part concerns
consumption. When the extra or surplus value, which has not been paid
and for which there is no corresponding money in circulation, is an
investment, it can be exchanged for other investments, like for like.
When the surplus value is consumption, it can only be exchanged for
investments abroad. India’s wealth was largely due to its cotton
fabrics. Growing the plant, spinning the thread and weaving the cloth
were a cottage industry that earned income for millions of people,
and part of the produce was traded for foreign goods. In the early
1800s English engineers invented mechanical systems to spin and weave
cotton. This led to cotton plantations in America, much closer than
India to the factories of Northern England, to the ruin of India’s
cotton industry, to the subcontinent’s subsequent conquest and its
colonial subjection. Trading consumption for investments allows one
side to accumulate capital and increase employment, while condemning
the other to stagnant or contracting capital and employment. But here
again the amount of surplus value for consumption outgrows the
possible trades for foreign investments. At which point the last and
only resort is consumer credit.
Credit
is a promise of future payment based on thin air. It is not unspent
income lent to and spent by someone else. Credit is not the
circulation of savings, of money. It is the guarantee that money will
be paid at a later date. Credit is a virtual monetary creation
limited in time. Credit is not money because it must be replaced by
money at some future date, but it acts like money by increasing
demand. Consumer credit can absorb surplus value for consumption,
until it is time for the credit to be paid in money. At that point,
money changes hands without a corresponding exchange of goods or
services (labour), and this non-exchange reduces demand. To fuel
growth in demand for surplus consumption with credit, the credit
granted must grow faster than demand (1). As the total amount of
credit increases, the credit granted has to multiply to maintain
growth in demand, until the size of the sum begins to cast doubts on
the system’s sustainability.
Money
allows the unequal exchange of value for more value. But the
supplement must come from somewhere, and each of its sources has its
limitations. At present there is a $152 trillion sovereign debt out
there (2), overshadowed by a $1.5 quadrillion derivative bubble based
on credit (3). This means two years of world income have been lent by
the part of humanity that has too much wealth to the part of humanity
that has too little, and about ten times more has been whisked up by
banks as ephemeral credit. These colossal sums have reached a stage
where they can no longer grow significantly (1% of a quadrillion = 10
trillion). And the interest they take is bleeding dry world demand.
It seems that the capitalist rule of getting more for less is
approaching its financial end-game and, as October has a history of
market turbulence, the world may be just a week or two from a
horrendous tipping point, a market crash shortly before the US
presidential elections that would set off some dangerous fireworks.
1.
Supposing that, over a given period of time, income and demand are
10. A credit of 1 is granted, which increases demand to 11. But, at
the end of the period it must be paid back. Income is still 10, so
demand is reduced to 9. To bring demand back to 11 needs a credit of
2, and to raise demand to 12 a third unit of credit must be granted.
Supposing income has risen to 11 at the end of the second period, a
credit of 3 must be paid back, which reduces demand to 8. And 5 units
of credit are needed for demand to grow to 13. Credit has grown to 5,
while demand has only grown by 3. If incomes do not grow the
difference is greater.
0 Comments:
Post a Comment
<< Home