Wednesday, October 30, 2013

Past debts, future instalments


Over the past thirty years, ever since Maggie and Ronnie began privatising their republics, the developed nations have sunk into debt by spending increasing amounts of their future incomes. And the two trends are intimately linked. To favour private capital under the cover of an entrepreneurial ideology, a new paradigm was instituted of reducing wages and taxes. However, labour and government are the mass consumers of society, and all productive investments end up, sooner or later, as consumer supply. Instead of paying wages and taxes, capital was encouraged to increase production. And, when supply increased, consumers were encouraged to supplement their insufficient means by borrowing.

Investing incomes instead of consuming them tends to overproduction and crisis. This fatality can be avoided by exporting consumption and importing investments, and/or by granting unlimited consumer credit. The industrial nations had developed their economies by using the first procedure, but the growing production of the last decades was, to a large extent, built in new developing nations and this has inverted the exchange. The developed nations found themselves exporting investments and importing consumption, which is when debts began to expand. Individuals borrowed to compensate wage freezes, governments borrowed to compensate falling tax revenues and nations borrowed to compensate commercial deficits. For a while all went well, billionaires thrived and multiplied, millions of people passed from extreme to simple poverty, but borrowing is cyclical and, since short, medium and long pay-back dates have begun to coincide, a growing number of borrowers are on the edge of insolvency. Stepping back means drastic reductions in consumption with all their knock-on effects. Stepping forward is a jump into the unknown.

The cancellation of debts has a long history, going back at least to Solon in 6th century BC Athens. But such drastic measures have more often been replaced by monetary creation, rising wages and inflation. In the past, debt and its reduction were the concern of a nation with its particular monetary system. That financial autonomy disappeared when debts were outsourced as a means of restoring commercial balances. The first to do it was the US under the Nixon administration, shortly after revoking the Bretton Woods gold standard, and when oil imports were suddenly costing much more following the 1973 oil embargo by OPEC. It was agreed that the trade deficit on Arabian oil would be paid with Treasury bonds. It was an offer the Gulf protectorates could not refuse. This successful formula was later extended to include all commercial deficits, with Japan, Germany and China. The UK, a nation of bankers, turned to selling complex financial products, and may have invented the mortgage backed “security”. Inside the euro zone trade balances were maintained with Treasury paper from the start, Germany being the major creditor. As for Japan, a nation of savers, it has had a commercial surplus for the past fifty years, and holds all its national debts and a fair slice of American ones as well.

The industrial nations old and new (G7 + BRICS) have criss-crossed their debts and intertwined their production and trade to a high level of interdependence. But the US, primus inter pares in wealth and power, believes it can decide unilaterally the value of its currency. The trouble is that the US dollar is America’s currency and, at the same time, it is the global measure of value. Governments in Tokyo can do what they want with the yen, as it only affects Japan. Whereas the planetary impact of Federal Reserve decisions is similar to that of the European Central Bank on euro zone members. US dollars are not a shared currency, as they are rarely legal tender outside of the US, and yet exchanges everywhere are labelled in and paid with them, and all the world’s moneys are constantly compared to them. The Cold War was a confrontation for world dominion, and the dollar was a powerful tool for holding America’s imperial dominos. The events of 1991 and 2001 changed all that into a global coalition of governments against subversion. Instead of subverting each other, East and West are now confronting subversive elements in their midst. Yesterday’s enemies have formed an alliance to face a common menace. They no longer oppose each other and their Cold War weapons are obsolete. And the dollar is no exception.

The leader of the Western world cannot become world leader. America’s role in the 20th century cannot be globalised in the 21st. The world’s demography will not allow it. And so it is with the dollar’s dominion. And yet the global market cannot function properly without a universal standard of value. It needs to display prices that have a common scale of measure, as do volumes, weights, distances, etc. The dollar could fill this function when the US was producing half the planet’s manufactured wealth (1945), or a quarter (1980), but as the fraction gets smaller (a fifth in 2012) there must come a time when an alternative instrument is necessary, a real world currency that is not subjected to the particular policies of any one nation. Unfortunately, the multinational coordination needed for such a system is inconceivable in these times of intense economic competition and multiple military interventions.

Nations around the globe are recklessly spending their future revenues. This path to insolvency was taken by Argentina, Greece and others with fatal consequences. But they are small countries, and their tribulations are not considered reproducible in the major economies, least of all in the US. The trouble with ballooning debts is that they take over the economy. More and more income is being lent instead of being invested in production, and is paying interest instead of consumption. Instead of producing and consuming, an increasing amount of the nation’s wealth is dedicated to lending and usury. A trend that is obviously auto-destructive, though it is difficult to predict at what point the process will fail, not so much when the bonded masses rebel as when the wealth produced can no longer fuel it, when there is no more to increase lending and the paying of interest. That stage cannot be far off. It may in fact already be in place, and is being held off temporarily by quantitative easing. The dollar, the euro and the yen are probably already living on borrowed time, under the perfusion of monetary creations by their federal and central banks. Stopping those flows would be fatal. Maintaining them can only prolong the agony.

A small fraction of humanity receives most of the wealth produced. Being unable to spend it, it is lent out to the rest of society, to corporations, states and consumers. But, as corporations came to depend less on borrowing for their investments (less taxes, lower wages, more profits and cheaper more productive technology), the lenders relied increasingly on governments and households to fill the gap and circulate their excess wealth (1). Except that corporate debts are investments and they return their value, whereas government and household debts are consumed and their value must be produced again (2). The huge transfer of income, from labour and state to property, created an imbalance of supply and demand that was restored by debt. But, since the debt peak of 2008, that imbalance has become increasingly obvious and detrimental. As household borrowing and welfare began to fall back, consumer demand slumped and is still drifting in the doldrums with neither power nor direction. And, as long as the drain of wealth continues, there is no reason why that should change. It seems that the debt solution to domestic and international inequality has run its course, “and it's a hard rain's a-gonna fall ”.


1. Alan Nasser, in accordance with Keynes, sees the emergence of cheaper more productive technology as a historic trend.
2. A tentative analysis of this in a previous post.

0 Comments:

Post a Comment

<< Home