An impossible decision
Official
inflation figures are based on the changing prices of consumer goods
and services. Keeping these figures as low as possible is the task of
central banks and statisticians. The first try to regulate the amount
of money in circulation and to control demand, the second pick and
choose what to include in their statistics. Inflation is considered
bad because it devalues fixed income assets such as bonds, and
because it incites labour to demand wage rises, which in turn puts up
prices and risks spiralling. On the positive side, money is spent not
saved and demand is buoyant, as opposed to deflation, where money is
held waiting for a better deal and demand is slack.
Inflation
is about wages, the living costs of labour and capital’s compelling
need of surplus value for rent, interest and dividends. When the
price of consumption increases, rising wages are cancelled out,
static wages are reduced and bond holders are out of pocket, while
capital gains are restored or multiplied. The diminishing exchange
value of currency is a consequence of the continual struggle over the
sharing of added value between capital and labour. The rate of
inflation rises and falls, but it has not been negative in the US
since the 1950s. In monetary terms the cost of living just goes up
and up, but other prices can go up and down with no apparent effect
on currency.
Shares
and real estate are markets where prices fluctuate all the time.
Sometimes they rise excessively and are called bubbles. Sometimes
they drop excessively and are said to crash. But their long term
trends move up faster than inflation and wages, as though they were
disconnected. Property is the concern of capital and surplus value,
not of labour. Should labour manage not to spend its entire wages, it
is supposed to lend these savings to banks and governments more or
less for free. Labour’s adventures into the property markets of
shares and real estate are the wind of bubbles, whose deflations
result in capital accumulation for some and lost wealth for many.
Outside
of amateurish speculation, the prices of shares and real estate are
determined by the return they bring on investment. And because
capital has the capacity to move around, this rate of return tends to
be the same for rent, interest and dividends. Moving capital from a
lower to a higher return will push down the price of the first and
hence increase its rate of return, and push up the price of the
second and hence reduce its rate of return. However, when the rate of
return of interest is kept artificially low, share prices rise in
consequence just as artificially. As for real estate, despite its
present post-subprime doldrums and huge stocks, low rates of return
elsewhere help keep prices synthetically high.
Added
value is divided between wages and surplus value. The first is the
income of labour and determines the price of consumption. The second
is the income of capital and determines the price of investments.
Both incomes have the same origin but their finalities are different.
Both come from the production and sale of goods and services, but
only the former affects their prices and the exchange value of
currency. The income of labour is the cost of its renewal. The income
of capital is surplus value, which is a part of the value added by
labour to the cost of investment renewals. Labour gets the cost of
its renewal. Capital gets more than the cost of its renewal and can
thereby accumulate. However, many authors have logically explained
that capital accumulation is not an indefinite process (1). At some
point in time the chains of production, raw materials and
infrastructure are assembled and the end products need to be
consumed. Machines to make machines to make machines to make
machines, is a series that has limits. And in an age of mass
production, the consumption must concern as many people as possible,
ideally everyone on the planet.
In
times of growth capital accumulates throughout society. When growth
falters capital concentrates in fewer hands. For capital to
accumulate, it must employ more labour without an increase in overall
consumption, though a different distribution usually occurs. If more
labour is employed and the cost of its renewal is unchanged, the
proportion of surplus value increases automatically. Once the
investment is in place its production requires consumption, which
supposes a reduction of surplus value. To avoid this, the extra
consumption can be sent abroad and exchanged for investments, for raw
materials, machine tools, etc. This procedure benefits some nations
and disadvantages the others. Some invest and others consume, some
employ more labour and accumulate wealth while the rest are jobless
and undeveloped. And it can absorb just so much consumption, at which
point consumer credit is introduced to take up the relay. But credit
for consumption has an exponential expansion that cannot last long.
All of which means that maintaining the high proportions of surplus
value that are inherent to the first stages of a growth cycle is
doomed to failure and can lead to chaos.
When
surplus value is invested in extra production, it ultimately
increases consumer supply and the necessary increase in demand means
its own reduction. But surplus value can also be invested in existing
production. Shares and real estate change hands, companies and
buildings are bought and sold. This goes on all the time, but it
predominates in phases of capital concentration. When the resort to
consumer credit has run its course and demand contracts, the weak
become preys for the strong, the middle stratum of society is pushed
down into precariousness and the spectrum of wealth is split by a
deepening divide. (Any resemblance with the present situation is not
a coincidence).
In
the past, wage and price inflation would cancel debt and stimulate
demand. That is no longer an option. Then the debt was long term at
fixed interest, and it was held by the nation’s citizenry.
Inflating it away caused mild political reactions and the occasional
electoral reversal. Nowadays debt is short term and can multiply
interest to match inflation, and a large portion is held by
foreigners who might decide to retaliate commercially. And, anyway,
the global network of production, trade and consumption is so
intricate that nations can no longer decide alone their wage
policies. The trouble is that at the post-credit stage of the cycle,
raising wages is the only way to get consumer demand going again. And
the only way to avoid the disturbing effects of inflation is to
increase wages to the detriment of surplus value. Faced with such a
dilemma, it is easy to see why the world’s leaders are so hesitant.
None of them dare break the sacrosanct rule of property rights to
rent, interest, dividends, patents and copy.
1.
For example this recent piece by Alan Nasser :
http://www.counterpunch.org/2013/05/03/the-economics-of-over-ripe-capitalism/
0 Comments:
Post a Comment
<< Home