A fork in the path ahead
Having
formulated the value produced as c + v + s, Marx remained puzzled by
it to the end. Constant capital (c) was invested in means of
production. Variable capital (v) was invested in labour. But where
did the surplus value (s) come from? Surplus value is capital’s
share of production. But if capital does not pay for it, what does?
At the beginning of the 20th century, Kautsky edited and
published Marx’s notes on surplus value and Luxemburg analysed all
the arguments, concluding that surplus value had its source in
capitalist expansion. However, without contradicting Luxemburg’s
deductions, the solutions to the enigma seem to be credit and trade.
In
the 19th and early 20th centuries, gold and
silver coins still circulated as legal tender. Monetary creation and
its circulation were still problematic, and the realm of commercial
credit was very secretive. All that has changed. Nowadays cash is
created electronically without a mint or a printing press, and credit
has spread to become the usual form of payment. And the virtuality of
electronic money has blurred the boundary between them. Things were
not so obvious a hundred years ago. But the exchanges inside
department I (producing means of production) and II (producing
consumer goods), and the exchanges between departments could grow on
credit, then as now. And they did, provoking the habitual periods of
growth and recession. Credit is a wager on future growth. It expands
the market by supplementing incomes. It stimulates demand, and
thereby encourages supply and investment. Credit increases spending
capacity, but the increase is conditional and provisional, and it
pays interest. Credit to businesses is essentially commercial,
discounting future payments. For investments, long term and perpetual
financing with bonds and shares is preferred. For consumers, credit
is the only possibility. But consumer credit, both private and
public, multiplies much faster than the demand it generates and
regularly overstretches itself. This means that growth based on
credit – as opposed to the growth that results from the enhanced
productivity of new technology with its own secular rhythms – is a
predictable cycle of ups and downs, with the different time scales of
credit moving sometimes in unison and sometimes in opposition. Credit
can supply the missing surplus value, but when several bubbles burst
simultaneously the consequences are chaotic.
Foreign
trade may refer to a monetary standard, but it does not concern
actual currency. It is an exchange of goods and services, a form of
barter that makes the settling of trade deficits so problematic. It
needs a transfer of bullion or, for the happy few, of Treasury bonds.
(The European common currency gave this possibility to 17 separate
nations, with dire results). But, even if the value of trade is
balanced, another aspect can have perturbing effects. This is due to
the division of production into departments, where a part of the
produce is consumed while the other part goes back into the
production process. The import and export balance of these two
categories has far reaching consequences.
Department
I: c + v + s = Means of production
Department
II: c + v + s = consumer goods
The
added value (v + s) of both departments represents the nation’s
disposable income that can be consumed or invested. But this sum of
added values equals the value produced by department II for
consumption. And investing part of it results in consumer demand
being insufficient. For department I to accumulate capital, it must
invest its surplus value and increase its means of production, which
means that department II has an excess of consumer goods. And, as
department I increases its production, it also exceeds demand because
department II is already producing too much. The only solution is
foreign trade. Consumer goods are exported and come back as means of
production. The end product is transformed into the primary product
to which more value can be added. Consumption is exported and raw
materials are imported, and accumulation by both departments goes
uninhibited. And, as ever more consumers are abroad, labour’s share
of added value can be reduced to the advantage of capital’s surplus
value. Nations that export their consumption accumulate capital
quickly, but their workers and their commercial “partners” pay
the price.
Consuming
surplus value goes against the ethics of capitalism. Investing it
makes demand for consumption insufficient. This dilemma is resolved
when consumption is exchanged abroad for investments. The most
obvious trade of this kind is guns, luxury cars and air-conditioning
for crude oil, but it can also be sports-ware for factories. In all
cases, one side accumulates and the other consumes. One side adds
value and the other uses it. One side expands its production, the
other has no incentive to do so and would be unable to compete
anyway. On the one side a part of consumption is not distributed, on
the other that part is distributed to regime supporters. Everywhere
there is wealth surrounded by poverty. This unfair trade was to
accumulate capital in a few industrial nations and leave the others
undeveloped. Then, a couple of decades ago, commercial competition
and the obsession with profit opened a breach. Outsourcing department
II to low salaried and environmentally indifferent places became a
necessity. But trading factories for clothing inverted the exchange.
Jobs and capital went elsewhere and consuming became a problem.
Capital
is a parasite that feeds off society. But it can only draw wealth
from the social body when its exchanges of goods and services are
expanding. If they contract, the parasite loses its source of
nourishment. When this began to happen, and when its lackeys
announced that the people had no money, capital replied, “Let them
use credit”. And, as is common with parasites, capital was
oblivious to the fact that it was killing its host. Having bloated
the world with debt to expand its dominion and its profits, capital
has reached the point where it is treading on thin air. Society’s
major task will be to avoid collateral destruction from an imminent
fall of capitalism at its highest stage. For the time being it looks
like a toss-up between a post-capitalist non-profit interconnected
world and a post-imperial dark age. Either humanity makes an
imaginative jump into the future, or it regresses to its sombre past.
P.S.
For an interesting Keynesian analysis of the end of accumulation by
Alan Nasser, which does not take into account credit and imperial
expansion :
http://www.counterpunch.org/2013/05/03/the-economics-of-over-ripe-capitalism/
0 Comments:
Post a Comment
<< Home