Trade and capital accumulation
Throughout
history foreign trade has enriched merchants and the nations they
traded from. It consists basically in moving goods from where they
are abundant to where they are rare, and doing the same on the return
journey. This sometimes needs intermediary stages and exchanges, and
the classic example is the North Atlantic triangular trade, when
cheap factory goods were shipped from Western Europe to West Africa
and exchanged for slaves, who were shipped to the Caribbean and
exchanged for sugar, which was shipped back to Europe. The general
rule was to get back more value than had been laid out. And, though
crossing oceans, deserts and mountains were dangerous enough to incur
losses, though home demand might fail and devaluate stocks, fortunes
were made and duly squandered.
Buying
to sell is about obtaining more value out of the two successive
transactions. But during the 18th century, value began to
be perceived as capital, and value as such could therefore be either
invested or consumed. Though not immediately apparent, this meant
that the ideal for foreign trade was to export consumption and import
investments. The English cotton trade gave the example: import raw
cotton, card, spin and weave it, add value and profit, and export it
for even more raw cotton. And so the steam driven machines in England
ruined India’s manual artisans. And even Indian cotton growers were
abandoned when plantations in the US adopted cotton as their cash
crop, making the transport shorter, safer and cheaper.
Trading
consumption for investments around the world has enriched the nations
that have practiced it. Profit, or surplus value, that part of
production for which there is no equivalent demand, could be sent
abroad and its value would come back as an investment, often as raw
materials, guns for oil. However, the process supposes that there are
winners and losers. The nation that exchanges its “surplus”
consumption for investments expands it production and accumulates
capital, whereas the nation that exchanges its investments for
consumption does not. In the first case, capitalists can make large
profits, as that share of production is sold abroad and does not
depend on the home market. In the second case, local production must
compete with the imported consumption and inevitably wanes, while the
nature and distribution of these imports is a cause of government
corruption.
Unfair
trading was the principle of colonial empires. But the cost of
maintaining colonial administration and order was then transferred to
the cost of maintaining a subservient local ruler and a semblance of
independent governance. The imported consumption that had provided
colonialists with a European lifestyle was kept going by the local
elites, and the flow of raw materials to the ex-colonial metropolis
was not interrupted. This has enriched the industrial nations, and
left their client nations undeveloped and dependent. However, some
nations did manage to industrialise. Taiwan and South Korea were on
the front line of the Cold War, which insured Western finance and
markets. And then, along came China.
When
the People’s Republic was proclaimed in 1949, China was in disarray
after a couple of centuries fighting European, American and Japanese
invaders, followed by a protracted civil war. The new regime had
support from the USSR, which resulted in some transfers of technology
and numerous Chinese students going to Soviet Union and Eastern
European universities. But Stalin’s death in 1953 and the ensuing
criticism of his politics and the personality cult around his person
provoked a rift between the two allies - Mao Zedong’s own cult of
Great Helmsman was just dawning – and by 1960 all relations were
severed. For about a decade China was isolated from the rest of the
world, with the exceptions of neighbouring North Korea and distant
Albania. But then Nixon visited Mao in 1972, Mao died in 1976 and
Deng Xiaoping came back to power in 1978.
China
had nothing to sell but its labour, and it went about doing that with
a vengeance. Applying the proven principle, it exported consumption
and imported investments on such a vast scale that it became the
planet’s workshop. This may have been Deng’s master plan, or it
more probably was the logic of profit capitalism when it gets its
way. China has massively accumulated capital. It has exported
consumption and imported some raw materials, plus a lot of factories
and technology. Or, more precisely, half factories, with the other
halves owned by businesses that were outsourcing their production
from North America, Japan and Western Europe. But the world market
could not absorb these infinitely expanding amounts of Chinese
consumer goods. So China has had to confront the problem faced by
profit capitalism everywhere: the fact that profits have no
corresponding demand and can only realise their value with credit
(See previous posting). The Chinese are now as deeply in debt as the
rest of the developed world and their exports have peaked. The global
economic motor is about to stall, and there are no alternatives in
sight.
0 Comments:
Post a Comment
<< Home